Four months ago, at the Jackson Hole conference, Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein proposed something of a financial catastrophe bond scheme for financial companies, in which they be required to meet a more stringent capital reserve requirement conditional on a financial catastrophe; the expectation was that this requirement might be met with an insurance mechanism of some kind that would cause the financial company to receive an equity infusion in that situation. They suggested a kind of secured insurance, but it seemed to me that a financial catastrophe bond (which they mention late in their paper) was both simpler and otherwise superior; the company would have a liability that, in the event of crisis, would disappear, converting to stockholders' equity.
The usual problem with insurance is moral hazard, and there's some of that here. There is some hope that, to a reasonable approximation, the financial company would not be able to instigate a financial crisis, but it does seem as though some behavior can be expected to reap worse whirlwind in case of financial crisis than otherwise, and that this sort of private behavior on a large scale intensifies systemic fragility. Historically financial crises are frequently preceded by bursts of poor loan underwriting; this is the sort of macroeconomic misalignment that finds itself in need of wrenching correction when the mania abates. A bank that finds itself choosing between loans that are relatively uncorrelated with the likelihood of disaster and loans that are feeding a mania (and are likely to go bad when it ends) will find the latter partially insured by the KRS scheme, and may well find them more relatively attractive than they should.
What seems perhaps safer to me is, rather than to have the liability disappear altogether, to have the liability convert to preferred equity. Concerns about an effective bank run or even an unwillingness of banks to lend should be alleviated just as well in this case as in theirs, insofar as the assets and liabilities pari passu and junior to senior unsecured debt work out the same. The common equity, however, is not shielded from the losses; the catastrophe bond claim remains senior to it. If equity drops dangerously low, the large subordinated class allows for a straightforward nondisruptive prepackaged bankruptcy, wiping away the liability only by handing the ownership of the bank over to the holders of what were originally the catastrophe bonds. It might, in fact, be worthwhile to give that preferred stock voting rights even before control of the company might pass to it; in any event where the liability is converted, it is likely that a good portion of the marginal dollar in assets belongs to that class rather than common equity. To avoid a bank's being permanently stuck with a capital structure that it may not like, it might make sense that such a preferred stock also be callable — it would be expected that calling the preferred stock would not be allowed by regulators unless the equity position of the company were comfortable.
Such a catastrophe-bond-converting-to-preferred-stock would surely be more expensive than ordinary unsecured debt, with which it would be pari passu if the institution fails idiosyncratically, but would likewise be less expensive than preferred equity. Which it falls closer to would provide a hint as to market perceptions of the correlation between the bank's risk and financial sector disaster risk. It should be somewhat cheaper than the original financial catastrophe bond variant. It also, insofar as management can be trusted to exercise its fiduciary duty to the shareholders, also largely eliminates the moral hazard problem mentioned in the second paragraph. It's a little bit more complicated (though not more complicated than the original secured insurance suggestion that KRS made), and it's more complicated in such a way that I expect there are complications I've missed. (One I've not missed so much as glided past is the disposition of dividends on that preferred stock.) Still, I think this is a step in a positive direction from what I've read before.
Tuesday, December 30, 2008
Monday, December 22, 2008
instruments of fed policy
I've been reading about the 1907 financial panic, and once again it looks as though a period of good times leads to leverage which serves both to intensify the correction and to make it more painful. I've come to believe that, where the Fed does see something that looks like a bubble, it should try to take steps that to thwart its being facilitated by debt; if it has fundamental support, the worst that removing leverage would do is to slow the equilibration. Likewise, the point of having reserve requirements for banks is that they be able to absorb some losses of capital without going below zero, but if you keep reserve requirements fixed, those losses of capital will result in going below the reserve requirements — you've simply moved the baseline from that standpoint. Zero is undoubtedly a special number, and solvency an important characteristic regardless of regulatory compliance — especially in terms of systemic stability — but in a time when banks are increasingly risk-averse of their own free will and many of them, while still solvent, don't have money to lend even to low-risk potential borrowers, it seems like we could benefit from lower reserve requirements.
The fed occasionally changes reserve requirements, perhaps most notoriously in 1937, when it felt the need to "mop up excess liquidity". That history notwithstanding, I wonder whether some interesting research could be done on whether the fed could effect policy with any greater success if it regarded regular changes in the reserve requirements as a normal tool to put to that service.
The fed occasionally changes reserve requirements, perhaps most notoriously in 1937, when it felt the need to "mop up excess liquidity". That history notwithstanding, I wonder whether some interesting research could be done on whether the fed could effect policy with any greater success if it regarded regular changes in the reserve requirements as a normal tool to put to that service.
home ownership for the poor and boundedly rational
It is obvious again that lending too much money to people with poor credit and financial means is a bad idea, and there is a resurgence in support for the traditional mortgage in which the purchaser makes a real down payment and a 30-year fixed-rate mortgage payment and won't be lent the money if those terms can't be met. Partly in response to this I've read and heard some sympathy expressed for poor people who have no savings but are "responsible people with good credit", suggesting that home-ownership is a privilege to which these folks should be allowed. I'm not a fan of home-ownership fetishization in general — there's nothing wrong with renting, folks, and there shouldn't be a moral opprobrium thrust upon it — but if we wanted to promote home-ownership in a responsible way for this class of people, there are almost certainly better and worse ways to do it.
I want to start by clarifying who we're talking about; I would suggest that anyone with no savings is not a "responsible person" unless — maybe — they have tenure or a government pension. (Someone just out of school has an excuse; the entirety of this discussion supposes we are talking about someone who is not inclined, on an ongoing basis, to put aside something easily regarded as "savings".) Supposing "responsible" means that they don't deliberately incur liabilities they can't meet, and supposing that in fact that whatever liabilities they do incur they will manage to meet — no unanticipated drops in income — then someone who can't save up a down payment but makes their bills almost certainly suffers from a form of impulse control in which money "lying around" is calling out to be spent. This impulse control also seems to be implicit in a lot of discussions of one value of homeownership (with a mortage) being "building equity"; if you can buy a house that costs $1000 a month in ownership expenses, including mortgage, of which $100 goes to "building equity", then (ignoring tax distortions for the moment) on average, over large expanses of space and time, you can rent a similar place for $900 and put $100 a month in savings, and build your equity in a savings account. The primary difference with the mortgage is that if you don't put in the $100, you're in default; you have somebody pressing you to build equity, which you don't have with the savings account. Economics types will sometimes refer to a "forced savings" component to a mortgage, and this is what one has in mind. Whether buying or renting is the better use of money is likely to be specific to the details of the situation — how long the individual expects to stay put, how much they value being able to remodel, whether there's a special reason to believe the house will appreciate in a way that's not priced into it, etc. — and is not simply a function of buying versus renting per se.
If we want to help people with this kind of impulse control, though, short of simply giving them money (which they would presumably spend anyway), it seems we need, one way or another, a forced savings mechanism. The obvious "solution", then, is a federal mandate that renters put money into a savings account every month, which money they couldn't touch unless they move. Perhaps better, though, would be a way to allow people to choose to commit to a forced savings plan. I have two variants that seem at least plausible to me.
One is essentially a no-money-down version of a shariah-compliant mortgage: the bank buys the house and rents it back to you, allowing you to purchase a share in the house on a pre-set schedule. This can be made to look very much like a regular mortgage, except that the bank goes into this explicitly aware that it is taking on the price-appreciation risk of the house. I'm not sure, in the United States, that banks are the most obvious institution to organize something like this; REITs are. They buy and sell and manage real estate as their regular business.
The second idea is more of a rent-to-own structure; the homeowner puts together the same sort of deal, in which a higher-than-market rent is charged over a five-year lease, and at the end of the five years the lease has an associated cash-out value and includes either the obligation or an option to buy with the cash-out value available as a down payment. This even more transparently lends itself to REITs.
In the former case the forced savings, as in a regular mortgage, was hidden in the ownership of the house in the form of home equity; in this case it's hidden in the cash-out value of the lease. In either case there's a long-run contract whose terms are breached by failing to make this conversion of liquid wealth into something less liquid. In both cases, the terms of the deal should be amenable to both a buyer and a seller on market terms, so that there should be no need for a government subsidy. It might be, though, that there's a status quo bias or coordination problem in the market, where there's little willingness to try these things because it isn't much done yet and wouldn't be worth working out for a one-off; it is also possible that the mortgage interest deduction and other terms of the tax code discourage this sort of thing. If the commanding heights in Washington think long-term home ownership for this class of people is a social good, creating some kind of tax incentive or subsidy to encourage REITs to do this might be an efficient way to do it with taxpayer money.
I want to start by clarifying who we're talking about; I would suggest that anyone with no savings is not a "responsible person" unless — maybe — they have tenure or a government pension. (Someone just out of school has an excuse; the entirety of this discussion supposes we are talking about someone who is not inclined, on an ongoing basis, to put aside something easily regarded as "savings".) Supposing "responsible" means that they don't deliberately incur liabilities they can't meet, and supposing that in fact that whatever liabilities they do incur they will manage to meet — no unanticipated drops in income — then someone who can't save up a down payment but makes their bills almost certainly suffers from a form of impulse control in which money "lying around" is calling out to be spent. This impulse control also seems to be implicit in a lot of discussions of one value of homeownership (with a mortage) being "building equity"; if you can buy a house that costs $1000 a month in ownership expenses, including mortgage, of which $100 goes to "building equity", then (ignoring tax distortions for the moment) on average, over large expanses of space and time, you can rent a similar place for $900 and put $100 a month in savings, and build your equity in a savings account. The primary difference with the mortgage is that if you don't put in the $100, you're in default; you have somebody pressing you to build equity, which you don't have with the savings account. Economics types will sometimes refer to a "forced savings" component to a mortgage, and this is what one has in mind. Whether buying or renting is the better use of money is likely to be specific to the details of the situation — how long the individual expects to stay put, how much they value being able to remodel, whether there's a special reason to believe the house will appreciate in a way that's not priced into it, etc. — and is not simply a function of buying versus renting per se.
If we want to help people with this kind of impulse control, though, short of simply giving them money (which they would presumably spend anyway), it seems we need, one way or another, a forced savings mechanism. The obvious "solution", then, is a federal mandate that renters put money into a savings account every month, which money they couldn't touch unless they move. Perhaps better, though, would be a way to allow people to choose to commit to a forced savings plan. I have two variants that seem at least plausible to me.
One is essentially a no-money-down version of a shariah-compliant mortgage: the bank buys the house and rents it back to you, allowing you to purchase a share in the house on a pre-set schedule. This can be made to look very much like a regular mortgage, except that the bank goes into this explicitly aware that it is taking on the price-appreciation risk of the house. I'm not sure, in the United States, that banks are the most obvious institution to organize something like this; REITs are. They buy and sell and manage real estate as their regular business.
The second idea is more of a rent-to-own structure; the homeowner puts together the same sort of deal, in which a higher-than-market rent is charged over a five-year lease, and at the end of the five years the lease has an associated cash-out value and includes either the obligation or an option to buy with the cash-out value available as a down payment. This even more transparently lends itself to REITs.
In the former case the forced savings, as in a regular mortgage, was hidden in the ownership of the house in the form of home equity; in this case it's hidden in the cash-out value of the lease. In either case there's a long-run contract whose terms are breached by failing to make this conversion of liquid wealth into something less liquid. In both cases, the terms of the deal should be amenable to both a buyer and a seller on market terms, so that there should be no need for a government subsidy. It might be, though, that there's a status quo bias or coordination problem in the market, where there's little willingness to try these things because it isn't much done yet and wouldn't be worth working out for a one-off; it is also possible that the mortgage interest deduction and other terms of the tax code discourage this sort of thing. If the commanding heights in Washington think long-term home ownership for this class of people is a social good, creating some kind of tax incentive or subsidy to encourage REITs to do this might be an efficient way to do it with taxpayer money.
Monday, December 8, 2008
systemic risk
Banks should be required to sell short large baskets of each others' securities so as to reduce the correlation of their own likelihood of failing with that of other banks in the system.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)